Drug evaluation and pharmacoeconomics

22


Drug evaluation and pharmacoeconomics





Safety, efficacy and economy


The volume, complexity and costs of modern medicines are increasing. The need to compare the therapeutic efficacy (i.e. benefits) of medicines with their potential to cause harm (i.e. risks) and the economic implications of these is of paramount importance to the pharmaceutical industry, to healthcare providers and to society. Pharmacists play a major role in evaluating the safety, efficacy and economics of medicines use.


At a macro-level, the pharmaceutical industry decides which line of drug development would best serve its shareholders’ interests. New chemical entities which show promise must be studied in clinical trials before they can be marketed as medicines (see Ch. 4). After products are licensed and marketed, society and its healthcare systems are then faced with difficult decisions about which specific patient populations to treat, or which new medicines to approve for use. Increasingly, decisions are based on economic evaluations, which attempt to calculate cost:benefit ratios for medicines in potential patient populations. In some countries, only medicines which have a clear cost-effective advantage over existing treatment are funded by government. In the UK, various organizations work in differing ways to examine this aspect of medicine evaluation. At a micro-level, clinicians (doctors, pharmacists or nurses) must then assess the relative harms and benefits of each medicine for individual patients. This involves consideration of factors which can affect drug disposition, efficacy and safety, such as concurrent disease states or other medicines, while also weighing up the risk of untreated disease and potential affordability. As pharmacists become more involved in selecting treatments, the importance of skills in evaluating all these factors to make individual clinical decisions increases. Furthermore, pharmacists are frequently required to evaluate the use of medicines in individual patients prescribed by others. This involves the further skills of drug use review and evaluation.


The techniques used in the evaluation of medicines for safety, efficacy and efficiency at pre- and post-marketing stages are summarized in Table 22.1.




Pre-marketing studies


In most countries, evidence of safety, efficacy and quality must be presented to government-appointed regulatory authorities before a new product can be marketed. Manufacturers wishing to market a product in the UK, can apply to the Medicines and Healthcare products Regulatory Agency (MHRA), or to the European Medicines Agency (EMA). Either body must be satisfied with the evidence provided before a marketing authorization (formerly called a product licence) can be granted. The MHRA and EMA have responsibility for assuring the public that all medicines which reach the UK or European markets have been assessed for safety, efficacy and quality. Cost issues are not taken into consideration. Efficacy has to be balanced against toxicity for each product and, while the MHRA’s evaluation includes the active ingredients of a product and its formulation, final decisions must also take into account the nature of the disease to be treated and the duration of the treatment. What is an acceptable benefit to risk ratio may differ for a medicine used to prolong survival in terminal conditions compared to a treatment for symptomatic relief of short-term symptoms.


Prior to clinical trials in humans, the pharmacokinetics and pharmacodynamics of any new drug are studied in animals to indicate therapeutic and possible toxic effects. However, because of substantial species differences in drug handling and response, new drugs must be screened in more than one animal species. Uncertainties in the relationship between the effects of drugs in animals and humans also mean that great caution is needed before progressing to ‘first time in man’ trials.



Phase I trials


These first trials are carried out in healthy adult volunteers, to determine the drug’s toxicity profile and assess tolerability. A dosage range is tested initially with a stepwise increase in drug dose being given to successive volunteers. Subjects in Phase I trials are intensively monitored to determine the nature and severity of any predictable dose-related adverse effects. Pharmacokinetic data are usually generated from both single- and multiple-dose studies. These may be used to assist in deciding the best method of administration.


These trials provide only limited safety data, because the subjects are healthy adults and unlikely to have any compromised drug handling ability. Thus, the potential risks of using the drug in patients at extremes of age, or in those with poor hepatic or renal function, are not known. There are also few subjects (e.g. 50–60), so only very common ADRs are detected.



Phase II trials


They are carried out in relatively small groups of target patients, usually within hospital departments specializing in particular areas of medicine. Their main aims are to test for efficacy and to identify an effective dose in closely monitored and controlled conditions. Phase II studies give the first indication of the likely value of the drug in patients, i.e. its efficacy. There is less emphasis on safety assessments during this phase, but the results will enable a therapeutic ratio (i.e. the balance between efficacy and safety) to be determined. Double-blind randomized controlled trials use a control group with a matching placebo to further assess efficacy. Phase II studies also inform the design of Phase III studies which are more comprehensive. Phases II and III combined may study 1000–2000 patients. The regulatory authorities closely control Phase II and Phase III studies, for which clinical trial certificates or exemptions are required.



Phase III trials


These trials examine safety and efficacy. They are generally large-scale studies comparing a new medicine with other treatments or placebo. Where possible, they should have a randomized controlled design, which is generally accepted as the least biased method of conducting clinical research. Assigning each patient randomly to either the new treatment or control helps to prevent bias (see Ch. 20).


Phase III trials are the main source of the information included in the summary of product characteristics (SPC) for the product. The conduct of clinical trials is subject to guidelines which cover ethical issues, trial design, the roles of investigators and sponsoring company and the storage and analysis of data. For every clinical trial which takes place, approval must be obtained from a research ethics committee. This committee will scrutinize the design of the trial, the information given to patients and the procedures for obtaining consent and that adequate compensation and insurance are available.


Safety is assessed by close monitoring of clinical signs and symptoms during scheduled clinical examinations and consultations, complemented by relevant laboratory investigations. Baseline pre-treatment data are compared with data obtained during periods of treatment with the study medicine and the experiences of treated patients compared to controls. However, systematic assessment of symptoms experienced by the patients included in the trials is not always carried out and a systematic checklist for patients to complete has been suggested. Even with the numbers of patients involved in Phases II and III, these trials can only identify type A ADRs that affect 1 in≥250 patients. Type B ADRs, which are not predictable from the drug’s pharmacological profile and tend to be rare, are more likely to be detected in post-marketing surveillance studies.



Post-marketing studies


Once the licensing authority is satisfied that a product is safe, efficacious and of suitable quality, it grants a marketing authorization, which means that the product can then be promoted to prescribers. This usually results in a large increase in the numbers of patients using the product and it is important that its safety is continuously monitored. The MHRA operates a system of post-marketing surveillance which involves spontaneous reporting of suspected ADRs, similar to that in many other countries. It is known as the Yellow Card scheme (see Ch. 51) and anyone can report suspected ADRs to the MHRA. Such schemes provide early warning signals of potential problems and can lead to hypotheses about associations between a medicine and an effect. These can then be tested using retrospective (e.g. case–control studies) or prospective studies (e.g. cohort studies). The main problems with spontaneous reporting schemes are under-reporting, difficulty in identifying new ADRs and the fact that incidence cannot be calculated, since there is no information on the number of patients exposed to the medicine. The benefits of patients reporting their ADRs to the MHRA have been formally evaluated and it has been shown that patient reports add to the usefulness of data obtained through reports submitted by healthcare professionals. European legislation now requires all member states to develop systems enabling patients to report ADRs to the national medicines regulator.


Case–control studies retrospectively identify patients who have developed a particular ADR and determine their level of exposure to the suspected medicine. This is then compared to a control group of patients without the ADR of interest. Case–control studies are smaller, much less expensive and generate results more quickly than cohort studies. They are used to investigate suspected ADRs identified by other means, e.g. cohort studies or spontaneous reporting and are particularly useful for confirming type B ADRs. They are capable of establishing whether an ADR is caused by a medicine, but cannot measure the incidence of ADRs.


Cohort studies measure the incidence of ADRs in a group of patients exposed to a medicine over a period of time and compare this with the incidence in a similar control group who were not exposed to the medicine. They are useful where a wide range of ADRs are associated with a single medicine, but are less useful for studying rare suspected ADRs. This is because large numbers of patients are required and must be followed-up for prolonged periods of time, which is very expensive and may result in patients being lost to follow-up.




Further clinical trials against other drugs/treatments


Most products are marketed having been subject to clinical trials in relatively few patients, which may have excluded certain patient groups. Furthermore, trials may have been conducted against placebo to demonstrate efficacy, but there may be no data on the comparative efficacy of a new product versus an existing treatment for the same condition. Data available at the marketing stage will have demonstrated efficacy, but not the effectiveness of the treatment in practice. In addition, basic research may highlight new theories of how diseases may be treated which require older medicines to be tested for efficacy in conditions where they have not been used previously. Examples of this are the trials required to assess the efficacy of aspirin for prophylaxis against stroke and beta-adrenoceptor blockers in heart failure. As with any other clinical trial, the design is important and the randomized controlled design is considered the most appropriate.



Evaluation of medicines in children


While medicines used in adults must have undergone this rigorous testing before reaching the market and coming into widespread use, this is not generally the case for medicines used in children. Since there are many differences in both pharmacokinetic and pharmacodynamic aspects of medicines between children of different ages and adults, medicines to be used in children need to be tested in children. Information should also be available to prescribers, parents and carers about using medicines in children. Manufacturers are encouraged to develop specific formulations and information leaflets and European legislation requires them to provide and share data. This should ensure the increased availability of medicines which have been specifically developed, tested and licensed for use in children, as well as providing more relevant information about efficacy and toxicity.



Herbal and homoeopathic medicines


Most herbal remedies are not licensed medicinal products and therefore no evaluation is required before they are marketed, but manufacturers can apply to the MHRA for a marketing authorization. Currently around 500 herbal products hold a marketing authorization and so must have fulfilled the same criteria of safety, quality and efficacy (or effectiveness) as any other medicine and be accompanied by a patient information leaflet. Efficacy has not been demonstrated for most herbal medicinal products, therefore manufacturers can instead have the safety and quality formally assessed and recognized through the traditional herbal medicines registration scheme (see Ch. 24).


Homoeopathic remedies can be registered under a scheme which again only assesses quality and safety but does not allow indications to be specified. Alternatively, some homeopathic products may be registered under a different scheme which permits specification for treatment of minor conditions, but to gain such registration, manufacturers must demonstrate efficacy.



Pharmacoeconomic evaluation of medicines


Once a product is licensed, decisions must be made about whether it should be used. Local decisions may be made by drug and therapeutics committees (see Ch. 23). On a larger scale, decisions on whether new treatments should be available on the NHS in the UK are made by NICE, the Scottish Medicines Consortium and the All Wales Medicines Strategy Group. Pharmacoeconomic evaluations play a central role in informing NICE’s decisions, so pharmacists may conduct economic evaluations and certainly need to understand them. It is important to appreciate how NICE’s work differs from that of the MHRA, who decide whether products can be sold in the UK, by comparing benefits to risks. NICE considers whether medicines should be bought by the NHS, by comparing benefits to costs, i.e. whether they are cost-effective.


Estimates of cost-effectiveness are derived from economic evaluations, which are the comparative analysis of two or more alternative courses of action (interventions) in terms of their costs and consequences. Where the intervention is a medicine, the economic evaluation is called pharmacoeconomics. In an economic evaluation, cost refers to the sum product of the resources that are used and the unit cost of each item. Consequences are the health outcomes, for example the impact of therapy on mortality or quality of life (or both). An appreciation of the basic economic principles is necessary to understand the methods used and the basis for economic analyses.



Basic economic principles



Scarcity and choice


Resources such as land, labour and equipment are finite compared with their possible uses, which are infinite. Therefore, no person or organization is capable of achieving all the good things they desire and some hard choices must be made. These choices may concern the fundamental direction of a person’s career or an organization’s responsibilities. They may also be choices about how best to achieve a particular goal. For a person, their salary is one measure of the resources available to them. They might not be able to afford both a new car and an exotic holiday, but must choose which they would get the most pleasure from (economists refer to this as utility).


An organization, such as the NHS, a hospital or a primary care organization, has a budget to fund new and existing activities. The use of this budget should be reviewed to make sure that patients’ health gains from the mix of activities are maximized. The purpose of economic evaluations is to inform decision-makers of the balance between costs and health gains in order that health outcomes are maximized at a population level.



Opportunity cost


When we make choices about personal or workplace activities, we usually spend money to engage appropriate resources. Considering only the amount of money spent as the ‘cost’ is a little narrow-minded. Economists would argue that the true cost (opportunity cost) of an activity is the utility from other activities that we can no longer afford. Thus, the opportunity cost of a person’s car is not £10 000, but might be the pleasure of an expensive holiday which was not taken. Similarly, the opportunity costs of one coronary artery bypass graft might be two hip operations not performed. Acting to minimize opportunity cost, therefore, ensures that the utility we obtain from using resources in a particular way is maximized. We call this efficiency, which is of two types: technical and allocative:



Few diseases are left completely untreated (because it would not be fair or equitable) but normally, efficiency demands that most of our scarce resources are used to maximize health gains for the greatest number of people. This philosophy is called utilitarianism. If people whose health status cannot be improved by health care are treated, there are fewer resources to help those who can benefit.



Supply and demand


Most people would not consciously consider ‘minimizing opportunity cost’ in their everyday lives. But they would usually try to get the most utility from the smallest amount of expenditure, which is the same thing expressed more simply. The price of goods and their availability are relied on as indicators of quality and desirability. The price mechanism for allocating resources works well if there are many buyers and sellers, each with similar accurate information about the goods and services on offer. However, the market for health care (unlike that for cars and package holidays) does not work very well. The reasons for this include:


< div class='tao-gold-member'>

Stay updated, free articles. Join our Telegram channel

Jun 24, 2016 | Posted by in PHARMACY | Comments Off on Drug evaluation and pharmacoeconomics

Full access? Get Clinical Tree

Get Clinical Tree app for offline access